The recent narrative regarding Greek debt sustainability has moved from the debt-to-GDP ratio towards the annual debt financing costs (interest payments + maturing debt). According to this analysis, Greece already enjoys very generous terms until 2020 and beyond and will only require small debt reprofiling measures in terms of interest rate payments and debt maturities after 2022. What is needed according to its creditors is for Greece to continue on the reform path, achieve economic growth and commit to credible fiscal measures that will allow it to maintain high primary surpluses close to 3.5% of GDP. Unfortunately that can only be achieved through tough measures on the pension front. «As long as Greece continues on this path, creditors will do their part» as the story goes.
In my view the above story is problematic, mainly because it relies on Greece achieving and maintaining a 3.5% GDP surplus target, a target which I believe is not credible in the long-run. In order to examine the subject from a theoretical point of view, I will use some well known concepts in economics, debt overhang and dynamic inconsistency.
Debt overhang is a concept usually used in corporate finance. It is based on the idea that, as long as the corporate balance sheet carries too much debt (which always takes precedence in payment over stock), stockholders do not have an incentive to contribute new funds in order to fund new investment projects if the proceeds are mainly used to improve the recovery rate of creditors. Balance can only be achieved if creditors ‘share the costs’ through a restructuring of the liability structure of the company balance sheet.
The same applies in the case of Greece. Its own ‘stakeholders’ do not have an incentive to contribute funds (in the form of high taxes or lower pensions/wages) if the increased surpluses will mainly be used to improve and ‘guarantee’ the recovery rate of foreign creditors. Given that Greece has a negative external balance (especially the cyclically-adjusted figure) it is an accounting fact that a primary surplus will involve a deterioration of the Greek private sector net financial assets position. Maintaining a 3.5% surplus target in the indefinite future involves a very large transfer of financial wealth from the Greek private sector to foreign official creditors with only a small part of the (possible) growth dividend staying in Greece. Most corporations would not accept such a bargain unless under threat, something which is more than evident in the Greek case where the Grexit threat has been thrown around for more than 5 years now.
Dynamic inconsistency on the other hand involves the idea that sometimes the solution to a dynamic optimization problem depends on the specific time when the problem is evaluated, which has the effect that a specific action time path is not credible.
A classical example is capital taxes. A fiscal authority might want to commit to low capital taxes in order to achieve large investment and growth. Yet at time t=1 investment has already been made and the temptation is high to increase capital taxes in order to enlarge fiscal revenue.
In a way, the same applies in Greece. In order to achieve debt sustainability, the fiscal authority must commit to a path of large primary surpluses. Yet, given the fact that such surpluses deteriorate the private sector position and the possibility of a negative shock hitting the economy, it is highly likely that Greece will have to lower its surplus (or even run a deficit) at some point in time. When the time of a negative shock comes, the optimal solution for the sovereign is to try and smooth the effects of the shock on the economy, not maintain a target that will only make matters worse.
As a result, especially given the need to maintain the surpluses for a very long time (in order to achieve debt sustainability), such a path is not credible. The fiscal authority will deviate ‘at the first sign of trouble’.
Combining the debt overhang with the dynamic inconsistency argument leads to a clearly unstable equilibrium. Both the sovereign and the Greek private sector (Greek stakeholders) do not have the incentive to commit on a high surplus strategy. Under completely rational behavior they have every reason to not damage their financial position and maintain the best possible growth rate. Any commitment on the high surplus strategy will not be credible but only a ‘temporary deviation’ in order to avoid short-term negative outcomes since the Grexit threat is still considered credible.
In my view, only a path of low future surpluses (accompanied by a large upfront debt restructuring) is a long-term credible strategy. Otherwise, we ‘ll keep on observing the current ‘stop and go’ path, with the Greek government implementing the least possible measures and its creditors using Grexit as stick and the (insufficient) future debt reprofiling as carrot in a repeated game with a non-optimal outcome.
4 Σχόλια
Comments feed for this article
18 Μαρτίου, 2016 στις 21:04
Vassilis Serafimakis
Σαν τα χιόνια, αγαπητέ κ Καλεβρά!
Γράφετε, «only a path of low future surpluses … is a long-term credible strategy.»
Όμως πλεονάσματα τού κρατικού τομέα, έστω και «χαμηλά», σημαίνουν ελλείμματα τού ιδιωτικού τομέα, μιά και η χώρα μας θα έχει για το ορατό μέλλον αρνητικό λογαριασμό τρεχουσών συναλλαγών.
Συνιστάτε ως «πιστευτή στρατηγική» μία στρατηγική η οποία εξ ορισμού θα καθιστά κάθε χρόνο ολοένα και φτωχότερο (ακόμα φτωχότερο) τον ιδιωτικό τομέα. Δεν μπορεί να είναι πιστευτή ή σωστή μία τέτοια στρατηγική.
Η μόνη λύση είναι η δραστική, ελλειμματική δημοσιονομική δραστηριοποίηση τού Ελληνικού κρατικού τομέα, μέσω δραστικών περικοπών φόρων σε φυσικά και νομικά πρόσωπα, έναρξη έργων επενδύσεων σε υποδομές, κτλ, δηλαδή κινήσεις που μόνον με νομισματική και δημοσιονομική αυτεξουσία τού κράτους μας μπορούμε να γίνουν.
23 Απριλίου, 2016 στις 17:09
everythingispolitics
Τεκμηριωμένη και πάλι ανάλυση με τεχνικά επιχειρήματα. Εφόσον Κώστα ισχύει αυτό που λες, που ισχύει σαφώς «Otherwise, we ‘ll keep on observing the current ‘stop and go’ path, with the Greek government implementing the least possible measures and its creditors using Grexit as stick and the (insufficient) future debt reprofiling as carrot in a repeated game with a non-optimal outcome.» θα ήταν ενδιαφέρον να έγραφες κάποτε μια τεχνική ανάλυση πως θα μπορούσε να βγει η ίδια η Ελλάδα, με τους καλύτερους δυνατούς ευνοικούς για αυτήν, από την Ευρωζώνη ως μια διέξοδος. Τη μόνη διέξοδο βασικά που βλέπω εγώ καθαρά από πολιτική σκοπιά που είναι σαφώς τελικά αυτή που κατευθύνει τα πράγματα και όχι η ορθολογική οικονομική ανάλυση
27 Απριλίου, 2016 στις 01:28
Crossover
Η πιο λεπτομερης σχετικη αναλυση που εγω γνωριζω ειναι αυτη του Μαριολη: http://www.theo-mariolis.gr/files/gr/Publications/pop_arthra/Programma_Oikononikis_Politikis.pdf
7 Δεκεμβρίου, 2016 στις 13:01
The death of economic logic | Economy View
[…] The end result will be that Europe will avoid having to perform any serious debt restructuring in the short-term, include the IMF in the Greek program and face the 2017 election cycle without serious concessions to the Greek side. It will insist on maintaining the 3.5% surplus target for the foreseeable future and place (again) all the adjustment burden on Greek shoulders regardless of the fact that such a target makes no economic sense. […]